Preface |
|
xix | |
|
|
|
|
1 | (2) |
|
Optimization and Equilibrium |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
|
3 | (2) |
|
|
5 | (2) |
|
|
7 | (2) |
|
|
9 | (2) |
|
Other Ways to Allocate Apartments |
|
|
11 | (3) |
|
The Discriminating Monopolist |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
14 | (1) |
|
|
15 | (1) |
|
Comparing Ways to Allocate Apartments |
|
|
16 | (1) |
|
Equilibrium in the Long Run |
|
|
17 | (1) |
|
|
18 | (1) |
|
|
19 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
20 | (1) |
|
Two Goods Are Often Enough |
|
|
21 | (1) |
|
Properties of the Budget Set |
|
|
22 | (2) |
|
How the Budget Line Changes |
|
|
24 | (2) |
|
|
26 | (1) |
|
Taxes, Subsidies, and Rationing |
|
|
26 | (5) |
|
Example: The Food Stamp Program Budget Line Changes |
|
|
31 | (1) |
|
|
31 | (1) |
|
|
32 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
34 | (1) |
|
Assumptions about Preferences |
|
|
35 | (1) |
|
|
36 | (1) |
|
|
37 | (7) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
44 | (4) |
|
The Marginal Rate of Substitution |
|
|
48 | (2) |
|
Other Interpretations of the MRS |
|
|
50 | (1) |
|
|
51 | (1) |
|
|
52 | (1) |
|
|
52 | (5) |
|
|
|
|
57 | (1) |
|
Constructing a Utility Function |
|
|
58 | (1) |
|
Some Examples of Utility Functions |
|
|
59 | (6) |
|
Example: Indifference Curves from Utility |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
65 | (1) |
|
|
66 | (1) |
|
|
67 | (2) |
|
|
69 | (1) |
|
|
70 | (1) |
|
|
70 | (3) |
|
Example: Cobb-Douglas Preferences |
|
|
|
|
|
|
73 | (5) |
|
|
78 | (1) |
|
|
78 | (5) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Estimating Utility Functions |
|
|
83 | (2) |
|
Implications of the MRS Condition |
|
|
85 | (2) |
|
|
87 | (2) |
|
|
89 | (1) |
|
|
89 | (1) |
|
|
90 | (6) |
|
Example: Cobb-Douglas Demand Functions |
|
|
|
|
|
Normal and Inferior Goods |
|
|
96 | (1) |
|
Income Offer Curves and Engel Curves |
|
|
97 | (2) |
|
|
99 | (5) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Ordinary Goods and Giffen Goods |
|
|
104 | (2) |
|
The Price Offer Curve and the Demand Curve |
|
|
106 | (1) |
|
|
107 | (4) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Substitutes and Complements |
|
|
111 | (1) |
|
The Inverse Demand Function |
|
|
112 | (2) |
|
|
114 | (1) |
|
|
115 | (1) |
|
|
115 | (4) |
|
|
|
The Idea of Revealed Preference |
|
|
119 | (1) |
|
From Revealed Preference to Preference |
|
|
120 | (2) |
|
|
122 | (2) |
|
The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference |
|
|
124 | (1) |
|
|
125 | (3) |
|
The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference |
|
|
128 | (1) |
|
|
129 | (1) |
|
|
130 | (2) |
|
|
132 | (3) |
|
Example: Indexing Social Security Payments |
|
|
|
|
135 | (1) |
|
|
135 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
137 | (4) |
|
Example: Calculating the Substitution Effect |
|
|
|
|
141 | (1) |
|
Example: Calculating the Income Effect |
|
|
|
Sign of the Substitution Effect |
|
|
142 | (1) |
|
The Total Change in Demand |
|
|
143 | (1) |
|
|
144 | (3) |
|
|
147 | (1) |
|
Examples of Income and Substitution Effects |
|
|
147 | (6) |
|
|
|
Example: Voluntary Real Time Pricing |
|
|
|
Another Substitution Effect |
|
|
153 | (2) |
|
Compensated Demand Curves |
|
|
155 | (1) |
|
|
156 | (1) |
|
|
157 | (1) |
|
|
157 | (3) |
|
Example: Rebating a Small Tax |
|
|
|
|
|
|
160 | (1) |
|
|
161 | (2) |
|
|
163 | (1) |
|
|
164 | (3) |
|
Offer Curves and Demand Curves |
|
|
167 | (1) |
|
The Slutsky Equation Revisited |
|
|
168 | (4) |
|
Use of the Slutsky Equation |
|
|
172 | (1) |
|
Example: Calculating the Endowment Income Effect |
|
|
|
|
173 | (1) |
|
The Budget Constraint Comparative Statics of Labor Supply |
|
|
174 | (4) |
|
Example: Overtime and the Supply of Labor |
|
|
|
|
178 | (1) |
|
|
179 | (1) |
|
|
179 | (3) |
|
|
|
|
182 | (3) |
|
Preferences for Consumption |
|
|
185 | (1) |
|
|
186 | (1) |
|
The Slutsky Equation and Intertemporal Choice |
|
|
187 | (2) |
|
|
189 | (2) |
|
Present Value: A Closer Look |
|
|
191 | (2) |
|
Analyzing Present Value for Several Periods |
|
|
193 | (1) |
|
|
194 | (3) |
|
Example: Valuing a Stream of Payments |
|
|
|
Example: The True Cost of a Credit Card |
|
|
|
|
197 | (2) |
|
Example: Installment Loans |
|
|
|
|
199 | (1) |
|
Example: Scholarships and Savings |
|
|
|
Choice of the Interest Rate |
|
|
200 | (1) |
|
|
201 | (1) |
|
|
201 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
202 | (2) |
|
Arbitrage and Present Value |
|
|
204 | (1) |
|
Adjustments for Differences among Assets |
|
|
204 | (1) |
|
Assets with Consumption Returns |
|
|
205 | (1) |
|
Taxation of Asset Returns |
|
|
206 | (1) |
|
|
207 | (4) |
|
|
|
|
|
Example: Gasoline Prices during the Gulf War |
|
|
|
|
211 | (1) |
|
|
212 | (1) |
|
|
213 | (1) |
|
|
213 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
215 | (5) |
|
Example: Catastrophe Bonds |
|
|
|
Utility Functions and Probabilities |
|
|
220 | (1) |
|
Example: Some Examples of Utility Functions |
|
|
|
|
221 | (1) |
|
Why Expected Utility Is Reasonable |
|
|
222 | (2) |
|
|
224 | (4) |
|
Example: The Demand for Insurance |
|
|
|
|
228 | (1) |
|
|
228 | (1) |
|
|
229 | (1) |
|
|
230 | (1) |
|
|
230 | (1) |
|
|
231 | (3) |
|
Example: The Effect of Taxation on Investment in Risky Assets |
|
|
|
|
|
|
234 | (5) |
|
|
239 | (2) |
|
Equilibrium in a Market for Risky Assets |
|
|
241 | (1) |
|
|
242 | (4) |
|
Example: Ranking Mutual Funds |
|
|
|
|
246 | (1) |
|
|
246 | (2) |
|
|
|
Demand for a Discrete Good |
|
|
248 | (1) |
|
Constructing Utility from Demand |
|
|
249 | (1) |
|
Other Interpretations of Consumer's Surplus |
|
|
250 | (1) |
|
From Consumer's Surplus to Consumers' Surplus |
|
|
251 | (1) |
|
Approximating a Continuous Demand |
|
|
251 | (1) |
|
|
251 | (1) |
|
Interpreting the Change in Consumer's Surplus |
|
|
252 | (2) |
|
Example: The Change in Consumer's Surplus |
|
|
|
Compensating and Equivalent Variation |
|
|
254 | (4) |
|
Example: Compensating and Equivalent Variations |
|
|
|
Example: Compensating and Equivalent Variation for Quasilinear Preferences |
|
|
|
|
258 | (2) |
|
|
260 | (2) |
|
Rationing Calculating Gains and Losses |
|
|
262 | (1) |
|
|
263 | (1) |
|
|
263 | (1) |
|
|
264 | (2) |
|
Example: A Few Demand Functions |
|
|
|
Example: CV, EV, and Consumer's Surplus |
|
|
|
|
|
From Individual to Market Demand |
|
|
266 | (2) |
|
The Inverse Demand Function |
|
|
268 | (1) |
|
Example: Adding Up ``Linear'' Demand Curves |
|
|
|
|
269 | (1) |
|
The Extensive and the Intensive Margin |
|
|
269 | (1) |
|
|
270 | (2) |
|
Example: The Elasticity of a Linear Demand Curve |
|
|
|
|
272 | (1) |
|
|
273 | (3) |
|
Example: Strikes and Profits |
|
|
|
Constant Elasticity Demands |
|
|
276 | (1) |
|
Elasticity and Marginal Revenue |
|
|
277 | (2) |
|
Example: Setting a Price Marginal Revenue Curves |
|
|
279 | (1) |
|
|
280 | (1) |
|
|
281 | (1) |
|
|
282 | (1) |
|
|
283 | (6) |
|
Example: The Laffer Curve |
|
|
|
Example: Another Expression for Elasticity |
|
|
|
|
|
|
289 | (1) |
|
|
289 | (1) |
|
|
290 | (1) |
|
Inverse Demand and Supply Curves |
|
|
291 | (2) |
|
Example: Equlibrium with Linear Curves |
|
|
|
|
293 | (1) |
|
Example: Shifting Both Curves |
|
|
|
|
294 | (4) |
|
Example: Taxation with Linear Demand and Supply |
|
|
|
|
298 | (2) |
|
The Deadweight Loss of a Tax |
|
|
300 | (6) |
|
Example: The Market for Loans |
|
|
|
|
|
|
306 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
308 | (1) |
|
|
309 | (2) |
|
|
|
Classification of Auctions |
|
|
311 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
312 | (3) |
|
|
315 | (1) |
|
|
316 | (1) |
|
|
317 | (1) |
|
|
318 | (1) |
|
|
318 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
319 | (1) |
|
Describing Technological Constraints |
|
|
320 | (1) |
|
|
321 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
323 | (2) |
|
|
325 | (1) |
|
The Technical Rate of Substitution |
|
|
325 | (1) |
|
Diminishing Marginal Product |
|
|
326 | (1) |
|
Diminishing Technical Rate of Substitution |
|
|
326 | (1) |
|
The Long Run and the Short Run |
|
|
327 | (1) |
|
|
327 | (2) |
|
|
329 | (1) |
|
|
330 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
331 | (2) |
|
The Organization of Firms |
|
|
333 | (1) |
|
Profits and Stock Market Value |
|
|
333 | (2) |
|
Fixed and Variable Factors |
|
|
335 | (1) |
|
Short-Run Profit Maximization |
|
|
335 | (2) |
|
|
337 | (1) |
|
Profit Maximization in the Long Run |
|
|
338 | (1) |
|
Inverse Factor Demand Curves |
|
|
339 | (1) |
|
Profit Maximization and Returns to Scale |
|
|
340 | (1) |
|
|
341 | (4) |
|
Example: How Do Farmers React to Price Supports? |
|
|
|
|
345 | (1) |
|
|
345 | (1) |
|
|
346 | (1) |
|
|
347 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
349 | (4) |
|
Example: Minimizing Costs for Specific Technologies |
|
|
|
Revealed Cost Minimization |
|
|
353 | (1) |
|
Returns to Scale and the Cost Function |
|
|
354 | (2) |
|
Long-Run and Short-Run Costs |
|
|
356 | (2) |
|
Fixed and Quasi-Fixed Costs |
|
|
358 | (1) |
|
|
358 | (1) |
|
|
359 | (1) |
|
|
359 | (1) |
|
|
360 | (3) |
|
|
|
|
363 | (2) |
|
|
365 | (2) |
|
Marginal Costs and Variable Costs |
|
|
367 | (4) |
|
Example: Specific Cost Curves |
|
|
|
Example: Marginal Cost Curves for Two Plants |
|
|
|
|
371 | (2) |
|
Discrete Levels of Plant Size |
|
|
373 | (2) |
|
|
375 | (1) |
|
|
376 | (1) |
|
|
377 | (1) |
|
|
377 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
379 | (1) |
|
|
380 | (2) |
|
The Supply Decision of a Competitive Firm |
|
|
382 | (2) |
|
|
384 | (1) |
|
|
385 | (2) |
|
Example: Pricing Operating Systems |
|
|
|
The Inverse Supply Function |
|
|
387 | (1) |
|
Profits and Producer's Surplus |
|
|
387 | (4) |
|
Example: The Supply Curve for a Specific Cost Function The |
|
|
|
Long-Run Supply Curve of a Firm |
|
|
391 | (2) |
|
Long-Run Constant Average Costs |
|
|
393 | (1) |
|
|
394 | (1) |
|
|
395 | (1) |
|
|
395 | (2) |
|
|
|
Short-Run Industry Supply |
|
|
397 | (1) |
|
Industry Equilibrium in the Short Run |
|
|
398 | (1) |
|
Industry Equilibrium in the Long Run |
|
|
399 | (2) |
|
The Long-Run Supply Curve |
|
|
401 | (4) |
|
Example: Taxation in the Long Run and in the Short Run |
|
|
|
The Meaning of Zero Profits |
|
|
405 | (1) |
|
Fixed Factors and Economic Rent |
|
|
406 | (2) |
|
Example: Tax Licenses in New York City |
|
|
|
|
408 | (2) |
|
|
410 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
411 | (2) |
|
Example: Farming the Government |
|
|
|
|
413 | (4) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
417 | (1) |
|
|
418 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
420 | (1) |
|
Linear Demand Curve and Monopoly |
|
|
421 | (2) |
|
|
423 | (2) |
|
Example: The Impact of Taxes on Monopolist |
|
|
|
|
425 | (2) |
|
Deadweight Loss of Monopoly |
|
|
427 | (3) |
|
Example: The Optimal Life of a Patent |
|
|
|
|
430 | (2) |
|
|
432 | (3) |
|
Example: Diamonds Are Forever |
|
|
|
Example: Pooling in Auction Markets |
|
|
|
|
435 | (1) |
|
|
436 | (1) |
|
|
437 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
439 | (1) |
|
First-Degree Price Discrimination |
|
|
439 | (2) |
|
Second-Degree Price Discrimination |
|
|
441 | (4) |
|
Example: Price Discrimination in Airfares |
|
|
|
Third-Degree Price Discrimination |
|
|
445 | (4) |
|
Example: Linear Demand Curves |
|
|
|
Example: Calculating Optional Price Discrimination |
|
|
|
Example: Price Discrimination in Academic Journals |
|
|
|
|
449 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
451 | (2) |
|
|
453 | (3) |
|
A Location Model of Product Differentiation |
|
|
456 | (2) |
|
|
458 | (1) |
|
|
458 | (1) |
|
|
459 | (1) |
|
|
460 | (1) |
|
|
|
Monopoly in the Output Market |
|
|
461 | (3) |
|
|
464 | (4) |
|
Example: The Minimum Wage |
|
|
|
Upstream and Downstream Monopolies |
|
|
468 | (2) |
|
|
470 | (1) |
|
|
471 | (1) |
|
|
471 | (3) |
|
|
|
|
474 | (1) |
|
|
474 | (6) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
480 | (2) |
|
Comparing Price Leadership and Quantity Leadership |
|
|
482 | (1) |
|
Simultaneous Quantify Setting |
|
|
482 | (2) |
|
An Example of Cournot Equilibrium |
|
|
484 | (2) |
|
Adjustment to Equilibrium |
|
|
486 | (1) |
|
Many Firms in Cournot Equilibrium |
|
|
486 | (1) |
|
Simultaneous Price Setting |
|
|
487 | (1) |
|
|
488 | (3) |
|
|
491 | (3) |
|
Example: Price Matching and Competition |
|
|
|
Example: Voluntary Export Restraints |
|
|
|
Comparison of the Solutions |
|
|
494 | (1) |
|
|
495 | (1) |
|
|
496 | (1) |
|
|
|
The Payoff Matrix of a Game |
|
|
497 | (2) |
|
|
499 | (1) |
|
|
500 | (1) |
|
|
501 | (2) |
|
|
503 | (2) |
|
|
505 | (1) |
|
Example: Tit for Tat in Airline Pricing |
|
|
|
|
506 | (3) |
|
A Game of Entry Deterrence |
|
|
509 | (1) |
|
|
510 | (1) |
|
|
511 | (1) |
|
|
|
|
512 | (2) |
|
|
514 | (2) |
|
|
516 | (4) |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
520 | (5) |
|
|
525 | (2) |
|
|
527 | (8) |
|
The Frog and the Scorpion |
|
|
|
|
|
When Strength Is Weakness |
|
|
|
Savings and Social Security |
|
|
|
|
|
|
535 | (3) |
|
|
|
|
538 | (1) |
|
|
539 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
541 | (2) |
|
|
543 | (1) |
|
Pareto Efficient Allocations |
|
|
544 | (2) |
|
|
546 | (2) |
|
The Algebra of Equilibrium |
|
|
548 | (2) |
|
|
550 | (3) |
|
|
|
Example: An Algebraic Example of Equilibrium |
|
|
|
The Existence of Equilibrium |
|
|
553 | (1) |
|
Equilibrium and Efficiency |
|
|
554 | (1) |
|
The Algebra of Efficiency |
|
|
555 | (3) |
|
Example: Monopoly in the Edgeworth Box |
|
|
|
Efficiency and Equilibrium |
|
|
558 | (2) |
|
Implications of the First Welfare Theorem |
|
|
560 | (2) |
|
Implications of the Second Welfare Theorem |
|
|
562 | (2) |
|
|
564 | (1) |
|
|
565 | (1) |
|
|
565 | (2) |
|
|
|
The Robinson Crusoe Economy |
|
|
567 | (2) |
|
|
569 | (1) |
|
|
570 | (1) |
|
|
571 | (1) |
|
|
571 | (2) |
|
|
573 | (2) |
|
Production and the First Welfare Theorem |
|
|
575 | (1) |
|
Production and the Second Welfare Theorem |
|
|
576 | (1) |
|
|
576 | (2) |
|
|
578 | (2) |
|
|
580 | (2) |
|
|
582 | (2) |
|
Robinson and Friday as Consumers |
|
|
584 | (1) |
|
Decentralized Resource Allocation |
|
|
585 | (1) |
|
|
586 | (1) |
|
|
586 | (1) |
|
|
587 | (3) |
|
|
|
Aggregation of Preferences |
|
|
590 | (2) |
|
|
592 | (2) |
|
|
594 | (2) |
|
Individualistic Social Welfare Functions |
|
|
596 | (1) |
|
|
597 | (1) |
|
|
598 | (2) |
|
|
600 | (1) |
|
|
600 | (1) |
|
|
601 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
603 | (3) |
|
Quasilinear Preferences and the Coase Theorem |
|
|
606 | (2) |
|
|
608 | (5) |
|
Example: Pollution Vouchers |
|
|
|
Interpretation of the Conditions |
|
|
613 | (3) |
|
|
616 | (1) |
|
The Tragedy of the Commons |
|
|
616 | (4) |
|
|
|
|
620 | (1) |
|
|
621 | (1) |
|
|
622 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
624 | (1) |
|
|
624 | (4) |
|
Relationships among Complementors |
|
|
|
|
628 | (3) |
|
A Model of Competition with Switching Costs |
|
|
|
|
631 | (1) |
|
Markets with Network Externalities |
|
|
631 | (2) |
|
|
633 | (4) |
|
Example: Network Externalities in Computer Software |
|
|
|
Implications of Network Externalities |
|
|
637 | (1) |
|
|
637 | (2) |
|
|
|
Sharing Intellectual property |
|
|
639 | (2) |
|
|
641 | (1) |
|
|
642 | (2) |
|
|
|
When to Provide a Public Good? |
|
|
644 | (4) |
|
Private Provision of the Public Good |
|
|
648 | (1) |
|
|
648 | (2) |
|
Different Levels of the Public Good |
|
|
650 | (2) |
|
Quasilinear Preferences and Public Goods |
|
|
652 | (2) |
|
Example: Pollution Revisited |
|
|
|
|
654 | (2) |
|
Comparison to Private Goods |
|
|
656 | (1) |
|
|
657 | (3) |
|
Example: Agenda Manipulation |
|
|
|
|
660 | (4) |
|
Example: An Example of the Clarke Tax |
|
|
|
Problems with the Clarke Tax |
|
|
664 | (1) |
|
|
665 | (1) |
|
|
665 | (1) |
|
|
666 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
668 | (1) |
|
|
669 | (2) |
|
|
|
|
671 | (2) |
|
|
673 | (1) |
|
Moral Hazard and Adverse Selection |
|
|
674 | (1) |
|
|
675 | (4) |
|
Example: The Sheepskin Effect |
|
|
|
|
679 | (5) |
|
Example: Voting Rights in the Corporation |
|
|
|
Example: Chinese Economic Reforms |
|
|
|
|
684 | (3) |
|
Example: Monitoring Costs |
|
|
|
Example: The Grameen Bank |
|
|
|
|
687 | (1) |
|
|
688 | |
|
|
|
|
1 | (1) |
|
|
2 | (1) |
|
|
2 | (1) |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
|
4 | (1) |
|
Changes and Rates of Change |
|
|
4 | (1) |
|
|
5 | (1) |
|
Absolute Values and Logarithms |
|
|
6 | (1) |
|
|
6 | (1) |
|
|
7 | (1) |
|
The Product Rule and the Chain Rule |
|
|
8 | (1) |
|
|
8 | (1) |
|
|
9 | (1) |
|
|
10 | (1) |
Answers |
|
11 | (30) |
Index |
|
31 | |